
11
Revista Médica Vozandes
Volumen 32, Número 2, 2021
EDITORIAL
epidemic itself and in the public health measures designed to
control it. Table 1 below summarizes the main implications of this
approach.
Table 1: Elasticity – Prevalence Values (Ep)
Ep Values Prevention demand Implications
Ep = 0
(Traditional
approach)
Little prevention More future prevalence
Ep near 0 Little prevention More future prevalence
Low Ep Little Prevention More future prevalence
High Ep More Prevention Low future prevalence
Ep much higher
than 0
More prevention Low future prevalence
Ep > 1 More prevention Low future prevalence
(Economic Approach) (Ex: demand for vaccine)
Source: Authors’ own elaboration.
Elasticity-prevalence is considered a major contribution of
economic epidemiology, for the understanding of the spread
of infectious diseases.
Government measures aims to increase the demand for
vaccination among the population, through price subsidies and
other similar policies. Programs that seek to stimulate this demand
are usually motivated by the low supply of vaccines, and the
belief that demands for vaccine is price elastic. However, if
demand for vaccine is elastic (sensitive) to disease prevalence,
it will limit price elasticity. According to Philipson T, et al. [8], a price
increase will lead to an increase in prevalence and, therefore,
an indirect increase in demand for vaccines. In this way, the
negative effect caused by the price will be compensated. If the
demand for vaccine is highly elastic (sensitive) to prevalence,
the demand will be highly inelastic (not sensitive) to price,
making vaccine price a secondary barrier to the rate of increase
in vaccinations. With this, the elasticity-prevalence is of foremost
importance, since it alters the calculations of the impact of price
subsidies aimed at stimulating demand.
The limitations that demand imposes on subsidies must always be
considered, proposing a reassessment of such subsidies. When
demand is elastic to prevalence, it has important implications
for the timing of implementing public health programs, as public
subsidies that encourage self-protective behaviour compete
with transmissive behaviour, that is, if the public subsidy is applied
too late, the private disincentive caused by prevalence has
already modied behaviour. Therefore, a more
careful analysis of the incentives that lead to the
occurrence of vaccine-preventable diseases
is needed, and the effect that public measures
have on the control of infectious diseases, even
those not preventable by vaccine. [9]
This brief editorial aimed to show how infectious
diseases can be evaluated from the perspective
of Economics. The Economic approach to
epidemiology has not sought to diminish the
importance of other approaches but seeks
to highlight recent theoretical and empirical
contributions that can be made by Economics,
and which have not yet received due attention
from many professionals mainly linked to Public
Health and Economic policymakers in this area.
The editorial sought to illustrate and indicate the
importance of information, incentives, restrictions,
and direct and indirect costs related to infectious
diseases. All these points are critical for evaluating
the real efciency of public policies for infectious
diseases.
With the advance of the new corona virus
pandemic and other infectious diseases
plaguing our region and countries, this area is
gaining notoriety within the community of health
economists and policymakers. Several efforts
are being made to understand the behaviour
of different populations in the face of the
pandemic and what can be done to change
individual incentives and restrictions to promote
an improvement in public health. Understanding
what drives people to take decisions regarding
specic diseases opens a range of options
and possibilities to contain the spread and the
worsening of infectious diseases, in addition to
help ght new epidemics.
Economic Epidemiology, its models, implications,
and empirical evidence are still in the initial phase
of its development, not having all its aspects fully
explored. Thus, we hope that this editorial will
encourage both health professionals, economists,
epidemiologist, pharmacists and other medical
researchers to carry out research in the area
and public policymakers to use this original and
novel approach as tool in the formulation and
evaluation of public policies in health and in
epidemiology in particular.
REFERENCES
1. Perrings C, Castillo-Chavez C, Chowell G,
Daszak P, Fenichel EP, Finnoff D, et al. Merging
economics and epidemiology to improve the
prediction and management of infectious di-
sease. Ecohealth. 2014 Dec;11(4):464-75. doi:
10.1007/s10393-014-0963-6.
2. Hauck K. The economics of infectious disea-
ses. Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Econo-
mics and Finance. Agosto 2018.
3. Gersovitz M, Hammer JS. The economical
control of infectious diseases. The Economic
Journal, Vol. 114, p. 1–27, Janeiro 2004.
4. Philipson T, Posner RA. Private Choices and
Public Health: The AIDS Epidemic in an Eco-
nomic Perspective. Cambridge: Harvard Uni-
versity Press, 1993.
5. Bhattacharya J, Hyde T, Tu P. Health Econo-
mics. Macmillan International Higher Educa-
tion, 2013.
6. Philipson T. Economic epidemiology and in-
fectious diseases. Handbook of Health Eco-
nomics, Vol. 1, p. 1761-1799. Amsterdam: Else-
vier, 2000.
7. Folland S, Goodman A, Stano M. The econo-
mics of health and healthcare. 7. ed. New
Jersey: Prentice Hall, 1994.
8. Philipson T. Private Vaccination and Public
Health: An Empirical Examination for U.S.
Measles. The Journal of Human Resources.
1996; 31(3), 611–630. doi:10.2307/146268.
9. Sadique MZ. Individual freedom versus collec-
tive responsibility: an economic epidemio-
logy perspective. Emerg Themes Epidemiol.
2006 Sep 26;3:12. doi: 10.1186/1742-7622-3-12.